Twelfth Conference on Global Problem
"The Rise of Japan and the Western World(I)"
Heita Kawakatu
Professor of Economic History
Waseda University, Tokyo
1. A new 'Asian drama'
A quarter of a century
ago, Gunnar Myrdal, in his Asian Drama (subtitled 'an enquiry into the
poverty of nations,') argued convincingly that Asia was subject to a
vicious cycle of poverty. There was little hope for development because
the low average income caused by the sheer size of population meant
that there were not enough savings to invest. The present East Asia,
however, stars in the world drama of accumulating wealth, and the centre
of that dynamism is Japan. When Japan experienced 'take off' in the
late nineteenth century, she was regarded as an exceptional case in
Asia, where most countries became subdued to the Western Powers. Now
Japan is followed by the Asian NIEs (Newly Industrialized Economies:
Korea, Hong-Kong, Singapore, and Taiwan), and these little four dragons
are, in turn, followed by ASEAN (Association of Southeast Asian Nations),
e.g., nations such as Thailand, Malasia, and Indonesia. If Myrdal were
to write a new Asian drama now, he would change the subtitle to 'an
enquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations.
Act one of the drama
is Japanese economic development. How did it all begin? It has been
assumed that Japan caught up with (and is now surpassing) the West.
There was, however, an unmistakable difference between Japan and the
rest of the late starters of industrial Europe and the USA. When continental
Europe and the USA started industrialization in the nineteenth century,
their infant industries had a high tariff protection directed mainly
against British goods, while Japan emerged as a power without tariff
autonomy. The tariff option to foster domestic industries was not open
to Japan until 1911 as the commercial treaties concluded in the 1850s
banned its use. It was Britain that remained the main exporter of industrial
goods, consisting mainly of cotton manufactures. Still, it was the Japanese
cotton industry that threatened Britain in Asian markets as early as
the first decade of the twentieth century. How was that possible?
In order to answer
these questions, this essay aims to address two points;
-- Firstly, modern
history has witnessed the emergence of two types of economic societies,
distinct from the old empires. These two types emerged at the extremities
of the Eurasian continent. One was the capitalistic world-system or
the so-called Modern World-System (according to Wallerstein), and another
was the Japanese economic society that came into existence almost simultaneously
with the former. Both moved to attain economic superiority over the
old Asian empires, that is to say, the West challenged such Islamic
empires as the Ottoman Turks (c.1299-1922) and Mughals (1522-1858),
while Japan challenged the Chinese empire. As Europe emerged as a power
seeking to dominate Islamic Asia, so Japan emerged as a power after
her victory in the intra-Asian rivalry.
Secondly, these two
economic systems were firmly established around 1800, without mutual
contact, through their respective 'production revolutions' of the 18th
century. The production revolution has been called the 'industrial revolution'
in the West, a capital-intensive and labour-saving type of production
revolution; while another type of 'production revolution' was carried
out in Japan characterized by labour-intensive and capital-saving techniques,
which Akira Hayami calls succinctly the 'industrious revolution.' As
a result, both the West and Japan were able to escape from the problem
of an outflow of treasure to the old empires of Asia.
2. Methodological
point of view
A brief explanation
of my methodological point of view is desirable at this point. What
matters here is economic development. J. A. Schumpeter in his pioneering
work on The Theory of Economic Development (1911) defined economic
development as 'the carrying out of new combinations'; different methods
of production can only be distinguished by the manner of the combination
of factors of production. The end result of the combined sum of all
the factors of production is all the products used in a society. These
products constitute the everyday life of the people and can be called
the product complex of a society. Each society has its own product complex.
When economic development occurs, that is to say, when a new combination
is carried out in a society, the combined sum, i.e., the product complex,
will change. Once the product complex changes, it will affect the manner
of life of the people. The concept of product complex is a modification
of the anthropological concept of the culture complex which refers to
the whole life of a people. The anthropological view of Japanese culture
-- which will also be the sociological one -- will certainly include
not only the tea ceremony, kabuki and no plays, but also the Sony video,
Toyota car, Nikon camera, andJaponica rice with chopsticks.
The product complex
is a term which refers to the material foundation of the culture complex.
The product complex of a society is the sum of all the material things
supporting the material life of the people. Adam Smith referred to it,
when he wrote in the first sentence of Wealth of Nations, saying "all
the necessaries and conveniences of life which it [every nation] annually
consumes, and which consists always either in the immediate produce
of that labour, or in what is purchased with that produce from other
nations." Karl Marx called it in Das Kapital "an immense
accumulation of commodities" to indicate the wealth of those societies
in which the capitalist mode of production prevails. The concept of
"product complex" is used here to refer to the entire combination
of goods which constitute the material life of a society.
Because of the strong
influence of Marxism, economic historians of Japan have focused on the
emergence of class, i.e., wage labourers and capitalists, paying little
attention to the material things used in everyday lives. The late Fernand
Braudel made detailed studies of the foods and beverages produced and
consumed from the fifteenth through the eighteenth century, in his first
volume of Civilization and Capitalism, 15th-18th Century. Alfred
Crosby in his The Columbian Exchange delineated the global dispersal
and exchange of New World products (such as pumpkin, maize, potato,
sweet potato, bean, cocoa, paprika, American cotton, and manic) and
also Old World products (rice, wheat, barley, oat, onions, radish, sugar
cane, coffee, indigo, grape wine, banana, olive, fruit crops; we can
include the cow, pig, sheep, goat, chicken, and horse). This inflow
of new products transformed the material underpinnings of life. It brought
about a revolution in European material life. This material revolution
was accompanied by their utilization and consumption in new form of
social organization.
Special attention
should be paid to a series of goods introduced from Asia, such as cotton,
indigo, sugar, tea, coffee, and porcelain. These became necessities
and conveniences in the material life of Europeans. Much of the demand
for the Asian goods had to be satisfied by imports and therefore had
to be paid for with gold and silver. These precious metals, in turn,
came mainly from the New World. During the first century after the discovery
of the Americas, Europeans were not interested in bringing anything
back except gold and silver. As much as one-fourth to one-third of the
huge volumes of these metals obtained from the Americas ended up in
Asian hands.
An overlooked fact
is that the trading structure between Europe and Asia was similar to
the one between Japan and the rest of Asia: Japan exported bullion to
and imported various goods from Asia. Just as the emerging pattern caused
a huge trade imbalance for the West with Asia, so Japan had a trade
imbalance with Asia. This imbalance remained unchanged until the end
of the eighteenth century.
These inflows of new
products caused not only substantial change in the product complex of
both European and Japanese societies, but also created a crisis in the
economies because of the corresponding outflow of precious metals. The
outflow of Japan's metals was so substantial that between 1648 and 1708
gold exports were worth 2.4 million ryo, while those of silver were
worth 374,000 kanme; between 1663 and 1708, exports of copper reached
114 million kin. The drain brought such a blow to the economy that the
only answer was to produce those imports for themselves. It was through
a production revolution that this import substitution was attained.
3. How it all began
According to Wallerstein,
the crisis of the 14th century created a conjuncture in which the Modern
World-System emerged, so went the economic society of Japan. When we
look back to the same period in Asia, we see that in the middle of the
14th century, the Mongolian empire was crumbling, being replaced by
the Ming in 1366. The Koryo dynasty of Korea was doomed to be taken
over by the Yi dynasty (Choson kingdom) in 1392, and the Imperial Household
in Japan was divided into two antagonistic groups, each claiming legitimacy.
In tandem with the crisis of the 14th century, a rising swell of overseas
advances occurred. As a result, Europeans and Japanese came to the same
geographical region of the world, the area known as 'the East Indies.'
There they engaged in intensive trading activities. The so-called 'Japanese
towns' scattered around the East Indies outnumbered the European so-called
'factories.'
These facts pose an
irresistible question. Why did Japan close doors in the 1630s, exactly
when the European countries began to widen their windows more to the
world?
During the period
between 1200 and 1600 China moved from the final decades of the Sung
dynasty (960-l279) through the Y?n dynasty
(1271-1368) and well on into the Ming dynasty (1368-1644), each achieving
notable developments. The Sung dynasty moved its capital to the south
sea coast in 1127, and that resulted in an expansion in Chinese imports
from foreign lands across the South China Sea. When the Mongols gained
ascendancy in the Y?n period, giving China
dominion over the world's largest empire, goods flowed into the country
from vast areas over the Eurasian continent. In the Ming period the
capital was also located on the sea coast during the first half century
until 1421. By the time of Ch'ing (1644-1910), products like corn, sweet
potatoes, tobacco, and chili were brought in from the Americas. From
the thirteenth through the sixteenth century, accordingly, China amassed
a wealth of goods through imports virtually from all over the world.
During the time of the Ming, the material basis for the livelihood of
the Chinese, i.e., the product complex of Chinese society, was radically
altered from what it had been.
In Japan, this was
a time of active exchanges with the Asian continent. Japanese pirates
preyed on Chinese shipping, from the mid-fourteenth century into the
second half of the sixteenth century, and dozens of missions were sent
to Ming China organized by the shogunate. Feudal domains, and religious
institutions were financed with the help of merchants in cities like
Hakata and Sakai; these exchanges were large in scale. This period thus
saw an unprecedented influx of goods from China -- sufficient to sever
the continuity in Japan's social evolution so that the everyday life
of the Japanese was transformed.
4. From currency
importer to exporter
Both Japan and Europe
replaced imports with home produced goods by the 19th century, and this
was a way of staunching the outflow of currency metals. One point to
note here is that before the drain of such metals can be a problem,
a country must first be in possession of them. Tokugawa Japan happened
to be the only country in the world that was self-sufficient in the
three main money materials of gold, silver, and copper coins and was
capable of controlling their distribution.
In the medieval period,
Japan had been importing huge quantities of copper coins from China.
This trade, which began in the mid-twelfth century, led to the import
of as many as 70 varieties of Sung coins. A mission to China in 1242
came hack with a massive load of copper coins said to have been equivalent
to the total volume of copper coins the Southern Sung could mint in
a single year. Thereafter the usage of these coins continued to increase,
and when the Ming replaced the Mongols, Ming coins were imported in
large amounts. Copper coins provided solely by China were the international
currency of Asia, in use in Korea, the Ryukyu Islands, Java, Vietnam,
and other areas of East Asia. Japan too was dependent on imports from
China for its currency throughout the medieval period. Japan's appetite
for copper coins was so immense that Shogun Ashikaga Yoshimitsu (1358-1408)
willingly turned Japan into a tributary of China in order to acquire
more coins from China.
In the Tokugawa period,
however, imported specie disappeared. The turning point came with the
minting of Kan'ei copper coins in the 1630s, while China became an importer
of Japanese copper. The shortage of copper in China and the need for
Japanese copper became a central issue for the Ch'ing dynasty (1616-1912)
toward the end of the seventeenth century. By then Japan was producing
many of the products it had imported from Asia, and the Tokugawa shogunate,
giving priority to the domestic needs for silver and copper, placed
limits on their export. In the 1700-1725 period, it is said that all
of the Ch'ing court's specie requirements were met with copper supplied
by Japan.
Tokugawa Japan, which
controlled the supply of its currency metals, gained influence over
China and other Asian countries. By exporting its surpluses, it displaced
China as the region's major supplier of copper currency. The appearance
of Japanese copper on the Asian market was an epochal event in Asian
economic history. As a money supplier Japan began to replace China as
a shaper of the Asian economy.
5. New combinations:
East and West
The story of cotton's
importation and subsequent manufacture will illuminate the point made
above, because it constituted an integral part of the Industrial Revolution.
Before imports of Indian cotton appeared in England, the masses dressed
mainly in wool. But because woollen goods are not suited to repeated
washing, they are not hygienic in that respect. Linen was too expensive
for the masses. Influenced in part by the Christian teaching that the
body is originally filthy, personal cleanliness was not people's main
concern until late in the eighteenth century. Unlike wool, cotton can
be washed easily; furthermore, Indian calico came dyed in various colors
and patterns. It was thus quick to catch on among the English. England
imported the Indian textiles and reexported them to other countries
in Europe and to Africa and the Americas, where they rose rapidly in
popularity. But because the imports had to be paid for, huge amounts
of bullion flowed out of England. The payments imbalance became so serious
that the government banned the import of calico in 1700, and when this
failed to produce the desired effect, it banned the use of calico two
decades later. The story of how this crisis was solved by the famous
inventions of Sir Richard Arkwright, James Hargreaves, and Samuel Crompton
who tried to perfect spinning machines, enabling England to produce
its own cotton fabrics, needs no explanation.
It took about a century
for the English to respond fully to the trade problem. To replace textiles
imported from Asia, cotton plants in the Americas provided an alternative
source of raw materials, and eventually the English devised spinning
machines which duplicated the Indian products. The process of the industrial
revolution was the process of developing domestic textiles as a substitute
for imports from India. The technological revolution was directed against
one of the old Asian civilizations. It was a production revolution that
undercut the need for Indian imports and thereby strengthened England's
economic ascendence in the Atlantic economy.
The ties that bound
Europe to the trading world of the Indian Ocean were also weakened in
other ways. Instead of buying such products as coffee and sugar from
Asia, Europeans transplanted coffee bushes and sugar cane in the Americas.
The realization that the New World could serve as a source of raw materials
triggered a drive to create a self-sufficient Atlantic economy, reducing
Europe's trade deficit with Asia. The statistics show that after 1810,
Europe enjoyed a surplus in its cotton trade with Asia.
In The Theory of
Economic Development, Schumpeter argues that economic development
results from a new combination of materials, production methods, goods,
and markets. The transition from the Middle Ages to modern times in
Europe was marked by numerous new combinations of precisely this sort,
including the organizational as well as institutional innovations as
advocated by Professor North, which provided the necessary framework
for them.
Did Japan experience
a revolution similar to that which occurred in Europe? Was there a vast
change in society's product complex through new combinations?
There was indeed one
such case, and it occurred at the same time that Europe was undergoing
its own revolution, just when Japan was shifting to seclusionism. In
the Age of Exploration, Japanese pirates and legitimate traders were
traveling far and wide, introducing to Japan the products of the lands
from the South China Sea to the Indian Ocean. Through exchange within
this region, the Japanese acquired new goods from the Asian civilizations
as well as tobacco and sweet potatoes from the New World. Just when
cotton, sugar, and porcelain were becoming daily necessities in Europe,
Japan was also importing these products, and through changes in the
products complex of the society, they touched off a lifestyle revolution
similar to that in Europe.
The product complex
was thoroughly altered, altering the culture complex. Historian Naito
Konan once remarked that the events in Japan prior to the 16th century
should be considered as belonging to the history of a foreign country!
Japan from the sixteenth century had great quantities of gold, silver,
and copper at home mines, and the export of these metals reached a volume
comparable to the volume flowing out of Europe. Eventually, however,
the production technology of the materials needed to make imported goods
was purchased or craftmen were brought back to Japan. Thus products
with their manufacturing technologies were shifted to Japan. By 1800
the outflow of currency metals was virtually halted. Almost all those
goods such as cotton, indigo, silk, sugar, sweet potatoes, porcelain,
etc. that had previously been imported were being made at home during
the course of the eighteenth century.
The revolution under
the Tokugawa regime involved new combinations. In combining the three
factors of production (labour, capital, and land), Japan opted for a
different combination from that employed in the West. 'The conditions
in much of the West, where labour was scarce relative to other factors
of production, made it sensible to maximize productivity with capital-intensive
production. But the conditions in Japan, where land was scarce compared
with labour, made it more logical to increase land productivity with
labour-intensive production. In farming, for example, the Japanese used
more workers in smaller fields. Neither of these two ways of combining
the factors of production is inherently superior to the other. Both
represented the best choices given the respective endowments of economic
resources. Instead of experiencing an industrial revolution, Japan in
the Tokugawa period (1600-1868) went through an "industrious revolution."
To summarize, both
Europe and Japan experienced a production revolution at about the same
time. The driving force in each case was the need to attain economic
self-sufficiency. Both the Japanese and the Europeans became acquainted
with new goods like cotton, sugar, and porcelain, but found that the
imports caused a depletion of their precious metals. To staunch this
outflow, both worked out new combinations of the factors of production.
The Japanese choice of the closed-door policy in the Tokugawa period
was motivated by the same kinds of factors that brought about the Modern
World-System in Europe. The development of Japanese economic society
was moving side by side with the evolution of the Modern World-System.
According to Wallerstein,
the formative stage of the Modern World-System were the years from c.1450
to 1640. This coincided with the time from the beginning of an era of
civil war (14671568) to the adaptations of the closed door policy Kan'ei
era (1624-44) imposed by the Tokugawa shogunate. The edicts issued between
1633 and 1639 banned Portuguese ships from entering Japan, forbade Japanese
citizens to travel abroad, and kept those Japanese already overseas
from returning home. By 1640 the Tokugawa system was firmly in place.
In this light, the Modern World System and the Tokugawa system were
in parallel not just by the creation of a new system of achieving economic
self-sufficiency but also by the timing of their formation.
When Japan was forcibly
opened and brought into contact with the Modern World-System, most historians
lay emphasis on how the Japanese embarked on a drive to catch up with
the West. But a careful examination as regards the reasons for Japan's
successful industrialization in the late nineteenth century will show
that the catch-up thesis is not that persuasive. The point to note is
that in forcing Japan to sign commercial treaties, the United States
and the other Western powers opened Japan not just to themselves but
also to the rest of Asia, setting the stage for free trade in the region.
The end result of this Western initiative was to be stepped-up trade
and an intensified competition within Asia.
With Britain as the
leading power, the governments of the West forced open the doors of
various East Asian countries during the nineteenth century. A major
goal of the commercial treaties they imposed on these countries was
the acquisition of export markets for Western products. In the case
of the British, this meant markets for cotton exports. In 1834-35 the
Governor General in India reported that "the misery hardly finds
a parallel in the history of commerce. The bones of the cotton weavers
are bleaching the plains of India." Indeed, Japan and the rest
of East Asia could have been colonized and suffered a fate similar to
India's. But actual events followed a very different course.
The Japanese were
not interested in Britain's cotton products, nor were the British interested
in Japan's. Britain specialized in cotton garments like underwear and
summer clothes, which were made from a thin cotton cloth woven from
long-stapled American cotton. But the Japanese, who did not possess
woolen goods, used cotton to keep warm in the winter. Their cotton clothing
was made from thick cotton cloth woven from short-stapled cotton. The
Japanese used British thin cotton cloth as an inferior substitute for
silks, and could rebuff Britain's export drive even without taking defensive
action.
Once Japan's ports
were opened, large volumes of shortstapled cotton flowed in from China
and later from India. Since this raw cotton was similar to the domestic
variety, Japanese cotton farming, which had flourished in the Tokugawa
period, was wiped out by 1900. However, Japan used the imports to spin
coarse yarn and weave it into a thick cloth, which was exported to China
and Korea. Three centuries before, Japan had imported cotton cloth from
China and Korea, but the "industrious revolution" in the eighteenth
century led to the contrivance of more economical production methods
and the cessation of imports. After Japan was integrated into the free
trade system by the West, exports began. Japan managed to take a lead
through the production revolution of the eighteenth century which was
the basis for this reversal of import flows into export flows. China
and Korea fell from their former high status to markets for Japanese
manufactures. The catch-up thesis, with its implication of a struggle
between Japan and the Western advanced countries, is not really on target.
Japan's successful industrialization was the product of a much older
rivalry with other Asian nations, one whose roots go back to the years
leading into the Tokugawa period.
The Japanese 'take
off' was the new combination of Western industrial technology on top
of the traditional industrious technique.
|