"An Essay for Studying the
Asian Development Model"
Akira Kojima
Deputy Chief Editorial Writer,
Nihon Keizai Shimbun, Inc.
Asia is now in the
midst of major changes. The region's economy is expanding, both driven
by and driving Japanese economic development. Awareness of the rapid,
fundamental changes occurring in the Japanese economy because of this
development is quickly increasing interest in Asia.
This has led to a
debate over whether there is an "Asian model" that can be
garnered from this development. Singapore's Lee Kuan Yew says that there
is not. Nonetheless, while there is no unique pattern of Asian development,
the overall region is developing in a manner than differs slightly from
"European-style" development. While there may be no "Asian
model," there are Asian characteristics that may be more significant
than commonly believed.
1. The Post-Cold
War World
An inquiry into the
overall position of Asia leads first to the question, What is the significance
of the end of the Cold War? Extensive debate on the post-Cold War new
economic order and new world order has proved inconclusive -- resulting
instead in the theory of "new world disorder." The so-called
"peace dividend" has also failed to materialize: the Cold
War's end and the coming of peace were quickly followed by outbreak
of the Gulf War, internal strife in Yugoslavia, and the appearance of
a new form of turmoil and instability in other regions as well. At the
same time, OECD members and other industrialized nations have nearly
all plunged into a prolonged recession against which Japan is still
struggling. It is amid such circumstances that the Asian region has
ascended so rapidly and begun showing signs of future economic predominance.
Terms like "the
peace dividend" and "the end of history" were tossed
about at the end of the Cold War, but have yet to be actualized. The
argument about the "end of history" even turned out to be
a prank. Today there are conflicts that are completely immune to the
nuclear restraint that worked during the years of power politics, with
no new ideologies or international mechanisms with which to respond
to them. Europe, meanwhile, is no longer as confident as it was when
European union was being debated in the early 1990s. Relations with
Russia have been particularly disappointing, as Russia, betraying initial
expectations that it might soften its stance and embrace the Western
European model, continues to show a reluctance to do so while at the
same time doing nothing to allay fears of nuclear proliferation.
One of the most well-known
debates on the direction of the post-Cold War world is that between
Kissinger and Brzezinski. Kissinger maintained an optimistic and active
point of view throughout the Cold War, while Brzezinski has viewed the
post-Cold War world with considerable pessimism. Comparing their predictions
with the way things are today, it would seem that Brzezinski's is closer
to becoming reality. This is apparent also from the current debate over
post-Cold War Europe's new type of poverty and strife, and it is from
this point of view that I wish to examine Asia.
In Asia, conflicts
involving actual shooting are becoming fewer and fewer, while such conflicts
persist in Eastern Europe and Africa remains unstable. Amid such international
circumstances, however, Asia's Indochinese Peninsula, once the heart
of conflict, is now moving toward peace, and even the Korean Peninsula
would seem capable of assimilating in the long run. The first aspect
of Asia that I wish to focus on is how a new economic dynamism is driving
political stability and stable diplomatic relations.
The primary reason
for Brzezinski's pessimism is poverty. Any examination into the causes
of conflict runs into the issue of poverty. Poverty breeds despair,
and despair leads to policies designed to turn public attention outward.
Even if this does not happen, an inflow of political refugees can create
political instability. Even if democracy has taken root, poverty creates
economic refugees. A regional conflict caused by poverty is not amenable
to containment by deployment of a few nuclear weapons. This makes the
question of how to eliminate poverty one of the most important issues
facing the post-Cold War world.
2. Factors Behind
Asia's Growth and Development
There is now considerable
interest in the reasons for post-Cold War Asia's rapid development.
Is it because of certain factors common to all Asian nations? How do
these factors differ from those in an EU-like region?
The World Bank's "Report
on the Asian Miracle" had a significant impact on world opinion,
prompting greater interest in the Asian reason. Recent debate on this
matter includes Paul Krugman's article in "Foreign Affairs"
titled "The Myth of Asia's Miracle." Mr. Krugman's own characteristic
views on Asian development suggest a deliberate attempt to arouse debate
on the issue. Chalmers Johnson's contribution to the February issue
of Japanese journal SEKAI (The World) asserts that a stronger Asia will
lead to create new problems in the world.
Growth in East Asia
cannot be explained merely as the result of intensive investments of
capital and labor, contrary to Mr. Krugman's claims, but instead requires
an examination of the region's productivity and technology, whose importance
Mr. Krugman has denied. With the Cold War's end, the nations of Asia
began to undergo an economic transformation, offering various incentives
to attract foreign capital, and today continue to compete against one
another with such incentives. Although this alone is not enough to attract
capital, there was also a major post-Plaza Accord currency adjustment
among the industrialized nations that coincided with the Cold War's
conclusion. Although the Plaza Accord was originally intended as a means
of compensating for certain principal nation's relative competitive
strength in other nations' markets, the extent of this adjustment and
the coincidence of rapid policy changes in Asia combined to stimulate
production in a way that made use of a work force that was inexpensive
and relatively leveled throughout the region. It was foreign direct
investment that bridged these two developments.
Direct investment
in Asia is considerably different from the EC's style of direct investment.
The EC has striven for expansion through a mode of investment whereby
similar countries (i.e., countries with similar cultural backgrounds
and in similar stages of economic development) invest mainly in each
other in order to strengthen their interdependence and pursue economies
of scale with a horizontal division of labor. Asia, in contrast, was
from the beginning a heterogeneous, diverse region with definite disparities.
In fact, development, resulting from the coincidence of an Asian policy
change and changes in conditions in industrialized nations, would seem
to be driven by these disparities. In other words, it was these disparities
that made direct investment possible, and Asia has expanded despite
a lack of an EC-like economy of scale because of its successful use
of its disparities, as in the division of labor within the production
process or among separate products. The term "ganko development"
("ganko" meaning a side-by-side formation and describing the
roughly equal pace at which the nations of Asian have developed) also
refers to this same utilization of disparities in which low wages become
one strategy in the division of labor among production processes. In
Asia there is now a multilayer mechanism in which one country, once
its wages rise, expands its capital to preserve its competitiveness
while at the same time making use of disparities between nations. This
is what differs from EU-style union. Also, the end of the Cold War brought
a realization that the Russian model was a failure, stirring the Asian
nations into action with an economic model closer to the West's. This
was one factor responsible for the development that is happening in
Asia today.
Despite Asia's religious
differences, differences in abundance of resources, and differences
in per capita national income, the nations of this region are moving
forward in unity, each striving for coexistence. This economic development
has initiated a positive cycle in which the incomes of different groups
are pushed upwards, driving further economic development. On these foundations
is developing a forward-looking, future-oriented climate.
In Asia there has
never been the kind of ideological conflict that pits one large nation
against another. Instead, Asian countries have tended to emphasis pragmatism
over ideology. For instance, after the collapse of the Soviet Union,
Vietnam looked at the development of the ASEAN member states around
it and made the practical decision to engage these nations constructively
rather than oppose them. I believe that Asia's rapid ascension after
the Cold War is essentially because of the concurrence of changes in
the times and economic changes both in Asia and in investing G7 nations.
Vague references to an "Asian model" are, I think, allusions
to the mutual trust that Asia is creating (debates about the future
notwithstanding) and to the sense of military and security-related stability
that has resulted from this mutual trust -- which contrasts with not-always-stable
bilateral relations in post-Cold War Europe, Africa and the Middle East.
A prime example of this stability is the ASEAN Regional Forum (ARF).
"Foreign Affairs"
recently ran an article, titled "The Pacific Way," written
by a Singapore diplomat named Mabubani. In this article he, too, suggests
a vague Asian model. His theory is that a process has begun whereby
Asian cultures linked by the Pacific Ocean will fuse in the sense that
the Asian socioeconomic model will coexist with other models. The term
"fusion" does not mean that these models will be integrated,
but that they will coexist without conflict. Asia, unlike the EC, is
not a union of closely related nations whose purpose is to eliminate
external elements of instability, and similarly the ARF is not a response
to an external threat, but rather represents an emphasis on mutual trust
among its members. Thus, it differs from NATO and the EC's economic
approach, and is uniquely Asian in that it is intrinsically open and
has the potential for considerable expansion.
This is only natural
in light of the fact that Asia has always opened itself to other regions
in the sense of attracting capital and technology. This openness is
the source of Asia's dynamism, and it would be self-defeating, with
respect to self-development, to shut out other nations. More-over, in
view of the fact that the region's current development has been driven
by this openness, there is no need for pessimism based on claims of
protectionism or exclusionist policies. Instead, this openness is an
extremely Asian element.
When the Cold War
ended, it was said that the world in the future would switch to a market
economy, the theory being that those countries that successfully introduced
private capital would develop. However, this is the private capital,
so it avoids the regions which often occur regional conflicts through
the theory of market mechanism. Ironically, the politically unstable
regions were also those that required private capital and investment
the most, and these regions have not benefited from the private-sector
vitality that has been the most important feature of the post-Cold War
world economic dynamism. Herein lies one dilemma.
There have also been
rapid cutbacks in the support that Russia and the West had provided
to poor nations during the Cold War years as a "carrot" to
entice them into their respective ideological alliances, in the belief
that whichever side had the most nations on its side would win. Absolute
amounts of ODA have also decreased overall, with the slight increase
in aid from Japan an exception to the rule. Allies of the former Soviet
Union were left to fend for themselves after Russia became unable to
provide them with aid. The same thing happened in Africa. With the end
of the Cold War thus ironically resulting in some countries' sudden
rise to prominence and other countries' being deserted, conflicts are
expected to worsen in areas where poverty is severe.
In contrast, economic
development in Asia has led to domestic stability and more amicable
relations between neighboring nations. In light of post-Cold War instability,
this process of Asian stabilization holds great significance for world
stability.
3. Issues in Future
Asian Development
Of course there are
also those who claim that Asia is actually unstable. This view, based
on economic conflicts of interest, is prevalent in the West. In rebuttal,
the above-mentioned diplomate from Singapore states with confidence:
"The Europeans, seeing Asia gradually catching up, have begun worrying
that they may be overtaken, and their argument is merely an attempt
to deny reality. The Asian model, however, is not just about following
Europe's lead. Europeans may believe that since conflict has broken
out in some parts of post-Cold War Europe, Asia, too, will one day face
the same kind of problems, but Asia will proceed in its own way."
In recent years, Asia's
commentators, emboldened by recent prosperity, have tended to be more
confident in their writings about Asia. The potential danger of this
confidence is that such commentators may have forgotten that there are
also unstable areas in Asia, and that friendly relations with the U.S.
will remain essential. How Asia should position relations with the West
(particularly the U.S.) will continue to be an important question in
Asia.
The second question
-- now that the nations of Asia are shifting away from import-substitute
production and turning to export-led production, with considerable combined
export capacity -- is, Which countries will absorb Asia's products?
Although economic development and rising individual incomes are enabling
Asian nations to absorb some of each other's products, a majority of
trade is still with non-Asian regions, and it would be impossible for
Asia to absorb all its own exports. The largest absorber of Asian products
is, of course, the United States. While Japan is the second largest,
it runs a net trade surplus with the rest of Asia, making it a minus
factor as an export recipient. In other words, Japan does not function
as an absorber of Asian products.
While standards of
living are rising throughout Asia on an overall basis, making everyone
happy now, I believe that at some point there will be backlash from
outside the region as Europe and the U.S. become unable to absorb any
addition Asian products and begin applying pressure. This has already
begun in the area of exchange rate adjustment, as is evident from demands,
made shortly after the Plaza Accord, that the NIEs revalue their currencies
upward. Similar demands are likely to be made on ASEAN members, along
with insistent calls for market opening. America's persistent calls
for market opening in Korea, for instance, seem to have generated considerable
anti-U.S. sentiment in that nation. Nonetheless, under current circumstances,
Asia will continue to need large absorbers like America, and so determining
how to position the U.S. and the role of Japan within the scheme of
things is an increasingly serious issue in Asia.
There are periods
of adjustment in any economic system. Japan's economic growth after
the end of World War II, for instance, has been a cycle of expansion
followed by recession, and the principal nations of Asia may at some
point enter such a period of adjustment. If Japan still has a huge trade
surplus with the rest of Asia when this happens, relations between Japan
and her Asian trading partners will not remain as congenial as they
are now. While Asia is still firmly convinced of the importance of friendly
relations with Japan, Japan, for her part, must acquire the wisdom needed
to look toward the future and strive for balanced relations with the
rest of Asia.
4. The Possibility
of a Yen Block in Asia
Regarding relations
with Japan and recent exchange trends (particularly the high yen), let
us now consider the possibility of a "yen block" in Asia.
Singapore's Lee Kuan Yew had always claimed that Asia has no need for
a yen block, but what do current developments suggest? Japanese corporations
are investing heavily in Asia, and the yen is being bought as dollars
are sold. While this is partly due to the dollar's drop in value, another
factor is Asia's need to pay back its yen loans, which now total roughly
3 trillion yen. Despite Asia's need for yen to make these large payments,
Japan's annual trade surpluses quickly absorb yen as soon as they leave
Japan, leaving an insufficient supply of yen for the Asian countries
that need it. Therefore, without a certain degree of yen liquidity --
both quantitative and qualitative -- there can be no yen block in Asia.
A yen block will become
a possibility only when Japan begins functioning as an absorber of the
goods produced by Asia's export-led economies. For now, however, Asia
is part of the dollar block. In terms of the relationship between the
dollar and the yen, it is the Japanese yen that faces a dilemma: Japan
cannot create a yen block because of a lack of yen.
There was a time,
about 15 years after the end of World War II, when the U.S. faced a
similar dilemma regarding the dollar's fluidity. At the time, the U.S.
was the world's overwhelming export leader, and the dollar was praised
like a god. However, America's trade surplus absorbed the world's supply
of dollars, leaving it in short supply. In order to increase the world's
supply of dollars, it created the Marshall Plan to divert roughly 1.8%
of its annual GNP to the rest of the world. Then, as an absorber, it
opened its borders to other countries' products -- even when those counties
adopted protectionist policies -- and purchased huge amounts of foreign
goods. This policy was too successful, however, and created structural
trade deficits in the U.S. Even with the dollar now too fluid, and the
dollar block in the process of correcting itself, supplies of yen, marks
and other currencies are too low to take the place of the dollar. Thus,
the yen cannot become an international currency, and Asia cannot become
a yen block. The precondition for a yen block is Japan's functioning
as a net absorber. If it fails to do so, a "Japan problem"
may occur in Asia as well. Some in the U.S. claim that Japan's economic
might is moving into the U.S. via Asia in the form of Asian imports.
If current conditions continue, this view will gain favor in the U.S.,
and a tough stance toward Asia by the U.S. would drag Asia into the
U.S.-Japan trade issue. This is my impression upon contemplating current
trends in Asia.
5. The Form of Asian
Development
A look at development
in Asia reveals no clear Asian model of development. For instance, the
trade and investment patterns of many developing Asian nations are completely
different from those of Japan during its period of development. Japan
was determined to make whatever it needed itself, and so excluded foreign
currency, allowing in only technology and borrowing capital from the
World Bank and similar institutions. Regarding trade, Japan's approach
was to use quantity adjustment to keep foreign products out, no matter
how inexpensive. Thus, Japan's postwar development model centered around
quantity adjustment, with no price adjustment necessary because of fixed
exchange rates. The Japanese government was extremely selective about
which foreign firms, no matter how competent, would be allowed to establish
wholly-owned subsidiaries. This policy lasted until about 1970. Korea
is the closest to this model, and Japan and Korea share a similar problem,
namely, their current difficulty in attracting foreign firms now that
they need foreign capital.
The rest of Asia,
in contrast, is allowing large amounts of foreign capital in. China
has been doing so somewhat selectively, but is still much less selective
than Japan was in its developmental stage. The most important between
the Japanese and Chinese models is that China's stance is to allow inexpensive
products in, and has from the beginning incorporated price adjustment
into its policy toward foreign capital.
A major difference
between the European model and the Asian model is the latter's departure
from the tradition theory of developmental stages, which holds that
each country begins with agriculture and becomes gradually more and
more advanced, working its way up to the processing of farm products,
then light industry, heavy industry, high-tech and finally services.
In Asia, however, labor, capital, factories and even brainpower moves
across borders, and once the development process is set in motion, a
variety of industries previously associated with the developmental stage
begin advancing all at once. This is the reason for the rapid pace of
recent Asian development. For example, an automobile industry suddenly
appears where none existed. Before, it took 50 years for a country to
go from textiles to automobiles, but a characteristic of today's Asia
is that there are already automobiles and computers. There are some
who call this the "accelerated" model of development -- that
is, going directly from the agricultural stage to the industrial stage
-- and I believe that what characterizes Asian development is the presence
of both the accelerated development process and the process whereby
industries representing different stages all develop simultaneously.
Rather than calling this the Asian model of development, a better term
would be the "1980s-and-1990s" model.
Note: This
article is an abstract of the report presented by the author at the
first meeting of GISPRI's "Study Group for Considering the Development
of Developing Countries in the 21st Century.
|